There are very interesting parallels between financial and network industries' regulation. Public interventions in network industries have
historically addressed a number of concerns. Market power is perhaps the most
prominent one, but there also concerns with externalities (positive and negative) and with asymmetric information. Equity concerns have also played a
role, for example in universal service policies or secutirty of supply. Some of
these policies have different time horizons: allocative efficiency concerns
have typically a short run horizon but universal policy or security of supply
have a longer run horizon. Some of the interventions operate ex ante (typically
regulation), and others operate ex post (typically antitrust). Sometimes ex
ante and ex post concerns are complementary and in other occasions theu are
substitutes. These policies interact: for example, it is difficult to maintain
universal service policy in the absence of new policy instruments when an
industry is liberalized. In this sense, network industries are not very
different from other industries, such as financial industries, where a
number of market failures and policy
concerns interact, as the global financial crisis has made clear. A lender of
last resort instrument (which has a clear distributive component) cannot exist
without instruments of monetary policy, and the lender of last resort
effectiveness depends on the effectiveness of policies of financial supervision
(which have to do mainly with asymmetric information problems). And all these
operates on an industry (banking) that is imperfectly competitive, and where
the degree of competition, together with the degree of insurance guaranteed by
the lender of last resort, affect the risks taken by agents (institutions and
individuals). In the global financial crisis, market power concerns have
clearly been trumped by the other concerns.
Politicians
are better at making decisions when the policy has far reaching redistributive
implications so that compensation of losers is important; criteria of aggregate
efficiency do not easily pin down the optimal policy; and if there are
interactions across different policy domains so that policy packaging or
evaluating controversial trade-offs is required to build consensus or achieve
efficiency. The introduction of
multi-dimensionality and distributive concerns in banking regulation and
monetary policy after the global financial crisis has caused Central Bank
independence becoming more vulnerable.
In the field of
monetary policy and financial regulation, although banking supervision and
monetary policy interact (as it is widely acknowledged after the global
financial crisis), given the difficulty of measuring output on supervisory
tasks, the systemic risk supervisor must necessarily be more accountable and
less independent than central banks are on their monetary task. And since
explicit incentives are not very useful, they must develop a strong culture and
ethic, a sense of intrinsic preferences for doing their job well, because
little credit is given if things go well, but a great deal of scrutiny and
criticism are given if things go badly (specially for some interest groups). Although the literature argues that a
single, large supervisory authority is better able to attract, develop and
maintain professional staff expertise, this has not been found to be the case
in other domains, where specialized agencies can offer a congenial environment
to the experts in that field irrespective of size. Enlarging the focus of
regulatory agencies has thus organizational and incentive costs. But as it was
seen with the financial crisis (for example with the Northern Rock debacle in
the UK), the central bank’s absence from supervision has also enormous costs.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
No comments:
Post a Comment